Factoring Liquidity Preferences in Startup Valuation

An assortment of United States coins, includin...

Image via Wikipedia

Great, so you’ve received a term sheet from an awesome VC, but it asks for 3x participating preferred equity. 3x participating preferred means that the investors get 3x their money back first, and then split the remaining monies based on their ownership percentage. So, as an example the investors might put in $3M at a $7M pre-m0ney valuation, for a post-money valuation of $10M and a 30% stake in the business. With a 3x participating preferred position, example exit outcomes are as follows:

  • Startup sells for $10M, investors get $9.3M (3x their investment (3 times $3M) and then 30% of the remaining value (.3 time $1M)), and other shareholders get $700k
  • Startup sells for $20M, investors get $12.3M (3 times $3M plus 30% of $11M), and other shareholders get $7.3M
  • Startup sells for $50M, investors get $21.3M (3 times $3M plus 30% of $41M), and other shareholders get $28.7M

How do you factor that type of liquidity preference into the startup’s pre-money valuation? As you can see by the three scenarios participating preferred equity (sometimes called double dipping) makes for dramatically different outcomes. On the surface it appears the investors own 30% of the business and invested at a $7M pre-money valuation but the numbers above show that with an exit at $50M or less, the actually percentage investors get is really in the 40 – 60% range assuming a decent exit.

One extremely simplistic way to think about participating preferred equity is that for outcomes less than 10x the pre-money valuation, every 1x of participating preferred takes the investors ownership position up 10-20% above their current position (e.g. from 30% ownership to 36% ownership for 1x participating preferred).

What else? What are some other ways you factor liquidity preferences in the startup valuation?

7 thoughts on “Factoring Liquidity Preferences in Startup Valuation

  1. I like one of the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants’ methodologies, specifically, the option pricing method. Basically, you treat the value of each series of preferred stock as a call option on the overall equity value, where the exercise (strike price) is equal to each series’ cumulative liquidation preference plus cumulative dividends plus participation features . This method inherently considers convertibility; if the overall enterprise value is greater than a particular series’ liqudiation preference (plus other preferences), that series will convert upon a sale. If not, they keep their existing seniority position pro forma. To the extent that the equity value is greater than the cumulative preference of the most senior series, all shares are assumed to convert to common and each series simply receives their pro rata share after all participation obligations have been satisfied.

    The arithmetic works both using the Black-Scholes as well as Cox-Rubenstein (binomial/lattice) frameworks. For technical reasons, I tend to prefer the latter.

    For some technical reasons, this methdology is imperfect, but it’s good enough both to satisfy the IRS and Big 4 Audits.

    — mike

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s